PATERNALISM AND
JAPANESE SOCIETY
Midterm
paper on R. Dore ’s chart
Nowadays,
reading a R. Dore’s book can be somewhat striking in the first
place. In fact, R. Dore was one of the numerous authors who wrote
about Japanese expansion and about the “Japanese threat” in
the 80’s. A threat perceived as a reality for many of the
occidental observers, until the beginning of the, still unresolved,
Japanese economic crisis, which put Japan under the opposite
spotlights (the study of Japan as a counter-model).
This
is nevertheless not the subject of this paper, which is to discuss
the author’s management theory. R. Dore upholds the idea of a
kind of inevitable uniformization of management toward an
“organization-oriented” system in which the power is more
shared and the feeling of “community” more patent, the one
that is precisely a fundamental root of the Japanese way of
management. In order to make a narrative explanation of this chart,
I will pick one specific path and link it with the Japanese case.
Taking only one part of a chart contains drawbacks and is a risk
to misunderstand his whole theory but I will try to take the most
representative and emblematic paths in order to explain the way
Japan accomplished its evolution in conformity with R. Dore’s
model.
In
the second part, I will discuss this theory considering the
Japanese specific cultural and historical backgrounds contributing
to create this particular type of management and moderating the
formal theoretical explanations of R. Dore.
Observing
the chart, a path seems to fit really with the Japanese case in
the road toward “power-sharing between employees and
shareholders: the “technological development” leads to a
“greater complexity of organization” and then to a “need for
more in-house training”. This specific training is the cause of
a “growth of organization-oriented labour-markets”, which
leads to “company organization of trade unions”. From this
results the fact that the management becomes based “on consent
rather than coercion” and eventually to the power-sharing in the
company.
Neverteless,
this path is only a bare fact. How did it work concretely, and
specifically how did it work in Japan? Let us now follow the same
path but from the case of Japan.
The
technological development is based on the second-industrial
revolution with the development of, among others, electricity and
coal-based production. This development first occurred in Europe
and in the United States. During the Meiji revolution, the
Japanese leaders decided to open their country, braking the
ancient Tokugawa rule of isolationism, and to adapt the best
elements of the West (not only technologically by the way).From
this point (after 1868), Japan began its technological development,
with the ultimate goal of not only catch up with, but overtake the
Western countries. It is then interesting to consider that,
beginning later, the pace of the Japanese development was much
faster than those in the western countries.
This
rapid pace of technological development rapidly led to the fact
that the little shops or family companies were not adapted any
more to fit with this process. In fact, big investments, and then
big companies able to realize these investments were needed. The
Japanese government (and it is typical of the Japanese development
process) played an important role in building and bolstering
merging and bigger companies.
The
“Zaibatsu” system was the solution adapted in Japan. A
Zaibatsu is a big company with a complex structure, comprised of
many companies, the central one being a bank, which provides money
to cope with needed financing.
Except
this financial factor, a technological development needs more
workforce (extracting coal, building a machine require many hands)
and a more diversified one (manual workers, specialists, engineers,
…). As a result, a more complex organization was required to
manage this growing and diversified staff.
As
the organization’s structure becomes more complex, there is a
necessity of workers with specific skills. That is, if a company
uses more advanced technologies, this company will need a new type
of workers: the usual craftsmen of feudal system are not adapted
any more, and employees able to use or repair or even produce the
company’s machines become a basic need.
Japan
coped with this evolution by creating “generalist” young
workers able to fit in any company. The school system (as R. Cutts
explains in “an empire of school”) in Japan was centered on
this approach: the child will be submitted to harsh and general
studies in which he will have to learn and memorize a lot of facts.
After graduating from university, they will be able to adapt in
every company, and the real specialization of the young people
will occur only after entering the company. And even if every
Japanese child didn’t go to university, the obligation of
education, at least for a few years, has been implemented early.
And there was a “national” agreement in this division of
education: the need for specific skills being better known by
companies, the companies, by in-house firm specific trainings,
will take charge of it.
As
a consequence, to employ a Japanese student was seen as something
a long-term investment: if the company provides specific training
to him, the goal for this company is to profit later of the newly
developed skill and to keep the worker for some time. But
reversely, the company had to offer something in exchange. From
this point, the labour market became more
“organization-oriented” as R. Dore says. In fact, the company
developed institutionalized career structures to offer safety for
the worker. In order to fit with this “long term relationship”
policy, two systems in particular were implemented: the life-time
employment system the seniority-wage system. To be employed in a
Japanese company didn not mean only “employment” but an
involvement for the whole life in the company which offered you
in-house training. And the salary scale fitted with this principle
in the way that the older you were, the better was your salary.
Every body agreed because as you were employed for life, you just
had to wait for your turn to get high salaries.
This
structure was not neutral because it led to the creation of a true
“community” feeling among the workers: the colleague was not
only a colleague, he was almost a member of the same family.
Indeed, the first principle who applies in this kind of
organization is equality. As every body have to climb the
hierarchical and salary ladder at the same pace, there is no use
to adopt any competitive or agressive behavior against the other
workers. And this sense of friendship and strong community-based
feeling among the employees reflected in the union’s
organization. As opposed to industry- or sector-based labour
unions (as those developed generally in the western countries) the
Japanese union were created and organized within the company,
reinforcing this feeling of community.
And
we have to note that the community feeling was not spread only
among employees but in the whole company. The “we are all on the
same boat” feeling was, and still is, very entrenched in the
Japanese companies. And as a consequence of al this (in-house
training, institutionalized career structures, company trade
union, community feeling), there was an increasing possibility for
the managers to manage in a more consensual way rather than by
coercion. A good instance is the trade union’s behavior inside a
company. Contrary to a western union, whose goal is to oppose
management and claim mew rights for workers, in Japan the trade
unions were very pacific and worked mostly hand-in-hand with the
management. Moreover, union’s leaders being usually promoted in
the management staff after a while, the relations were basically
consensual.
The
final stage is obvious: if the management is a consensual one and
the company “family-like”, the way to power-sharing between
employees and shareholder representative is already marked out.
Even if this path remains for the inmost part rarely materialized
hitherto, it is easily understandable that giving power to
employees is the next step to adopt for a “family-like”
company with strong ties between employees and management.
The
R. Dore’s chart is now more explicit in the way we have
explained how the different steps were linked together and led to
a power-sharing between shareholders and employees. The point now
is to know if this path is correct or at least if it is arguable
or not.
It
will be very presumptuous to give a judgement on R. Dore’s chart.
Mostly because having chosen only one path of this chart
inevitably limits its meaning and does not enable to make a
overall judgment on it. But still, it is possible to discuss it
considering other factors and facing it with the Japanese reality.
The
first point I would like to discuss is that this chart, though
very complete, remains a theory. In fact, differences between
theory and reality are still huge in the way theories only
represent the ideal way to follow to attend a definite goal. But
in reality the link between paths is not so easy to achieve. As an
example, we could say that this idealistic form of power-sharing
between employees and share-holders is not a common practice, even
in Japan, a country where so-called “paternalism” is spread
inside companies. For such a change to occur, other factors(conservatism,
management characters,…) have to be taken into considerations,
and these “psychological” could never be formalized in any
theories.
Furthermore,
R. Dore is putting at the root of this way toward the
“industrial democracy” the technological development. If the
technological development played undoubtedly an important part in
the evolution of the organizations and of the management, it was
not the only factor. In fact, the cultural factor played a
critical part also, probably even more important than the one
played by technological development, and especially in Japan. The
Japanese feudal system was based on the concept of paternalism (恩情主義)
that of devotion and duty toward the parents(孝)and
reciprocally that of respect and obligation toward the children(恩).
These cultural backgrounds evolved as the time passed and the
figures of respects varied from the Daimyo to the emperor. And
after the beginning of the Japanese economic development, these
cultural traditions have been reinterpreted inside the companies:
the figure of the father was played by the chairman of the company
whereas the children’s role was attributed to the employees. And
this point is a key to understand the way the relations worked in
a Japanese company: it is not only by a mechanical path of
organizational complexity that the in-house training and then the
institutional career structures took roots. There was a deep
cultural tradition behind it and that kind of community
relationship inside a group was much more than a consequence of
technological development, it preceded it and accompanied it to
forge the so-called “Japanese organization-oriented
organizations”.
In
addition, a third factor took an important part in the process
leading to the Japanese style of management. I should call it the
“contextual factor” or the historical one. In fact, even if
the “会社人間culture”
is a reality in Japan with a familial style of management, it was
not a neutral principle. As A. Gordon explains, this Japanese
“beautiful culture” have been contextually used by the
managers of “Japan Inc.”. It means that they have exploited
this trend to legitimize harsh conditions of work, increasing
production and social peace. Concretely, this emphasizing of
“familial values” was a way to avoid two different threats, or
perceived threats, for Japanese companies’ heads. First, they
wanted to avoid the western modernization and especially the
modernization of management, in order to keep their positions and
prevent from any movement or reform(this point is besides
interesting because this conservatism could be, still now,
entrenched and one of the cause of the Japan’s ongoing crisis).
Secondly, they wanted to avoid the creation of labor unions in the
companies(which explains the struggles occurring before the
implementation of the labor law in, and out, the Diet). To
idealize a family ideal in each company was a strong hint to kill
in the egg every feeling of emancipation of the workers. And it
worked well, for some time.
In
conclusion, we can say that, even if the R. Dore chart is really
interesting and highlights the non-arguable link that leads the
technological development to a more shared power in a company, it
remains a theory. Indeed, theories are useful to synthesize and
clarify facts, but they remain of little sense and meaning until
they are combined with cultural and social backgrounds. Yes, Japan
followed this path, but it was not as fluid as a chart, it had to
deal with a “paternalistic background” going back to feudal
times, and with managers’ interests as well. It was a process
going onwards and backwards to finally achieve along the years, to
finally ends up in what is called “the Japanese way of
management”, a system anyway more diverse than the expression
gives to understand.
Pierre
DANIEL
Waseda
University - Mai 2003
|